Final answer:
In a perfectly competitive market, soybean production that includes a negative externality such as pollution from fertilizers leads to a higher quantity produced than the social optimum, indicating market failure. The intersection of the marginal social cost (MSC), which accounts for externalities, with demand represents the socially optimum production point, which is lower than the market equilibrium based solely on marginal private cost (MPC).
Step-by-step explanation:
Soybeans, as described in this context, are produced in a perfectly competitive market, where the product is fairly homogenous, and producers are price takers. In such a market, the interaction of demand and supply typically coordinates social costs and benefits effectively. However, the presence of a negative externality, such as pollution from fertilizer runoff, throws a wrench into this ideal interaction.
To illustrate the impact of a negative externality in a perfectly competitive market, consider a graph where the horizontal axis represents the quantity of soybeans, and the vertical axis represents the price. The supply curve, representing marginal private cost (MPC), slopes upward showing that as producers offer more soybeans, the cost to produce each additional unit increases. However, this supply curve does not take into account the social cost, which includes the negative externality of pollution.
To account for this, one must include the marginal social cost (MSC) in the graph, which is typically above the MPC due to the added external costs of pollution. The intersection of MSC and demand would show the socially optimal point of production, which is typically at a lower quantity and higher price than what the market with only MPC would determine. This discrepancy highlights the market failure due to the negative externality since the market equilibrium reflects neither the true cost of production nor the social optimum.